顯示具有 UK 標籤的文章。 顯示所有文章
顯示具有 UK 標籤的文章。 顯示所有文章

2011年7月5日 星期二

大英帝國的例子


以史為鑑,大英帝國的興亡,大概可以作為大美帝國的前車。歷史學家一般以1850年為大英號的稱霸開始,然後以1997年香港回歸中國作為終結,為時一百五十年,但衰落的開始在哪一點?

如果1842年第一次鴉片戰爭,大英號收到大清號的2100萬両,是富甲天下的開始,1860年二次鴉片戰爭就是英法聯國。1900年的八國聯軍,英國已不是獨霸,《辛丑條約》是以中法文簽訂,以字母先後排名,GB可排在法國F之後。

1900年開始,世上已開始懷疑英國獨大的局面會變化;以經濟實力而論,美國GDP已是世界第一、大清第二、英國第三,但軍力仍以英國為首。

第一次世界大戰後,英國努力保住世界老大地位,1924年是頂點,大英號有五十八個成員,人口四億,地中海仍是大英號的世界;1925年,大英號越過中國,成為世界第二。

然而,美國稱雄已不可擋,第二次大戰後的二十二年才是最大下降,大英號的人口二十二年間由七億降至五千萬,其中三百萬在香港,情況維持到1997年,香港還增至六百萬人。

2000年再結賬,世間最大經濟體已是美國、日本、中國、德國和法國號頭五名,大英號只能排第六,何時被金磚四國超越,只是時間問題。

總結:大英號雄霸一百年後開始下落,掙扎求存二十年,1956年失去蘇彝士運河,1967年撤離也門阿丁港都是轉捩點,由1924年的頂點到完結,也有四分三世紀呢!

2011年6月26日 星期日

Lloyds has largest exposure to risky loans

By Sharlene Goff and Norma Cohen

Lloyds Banking Group’s exposure to the riskiest kind of mortgages is more than double that of any of its top five rivals in what is potentially a ticking time bomb for Britain’s largest high-street lender.

Data published last week by the Bank of England showed that loans representing more than a quarter of Lloyds’ mortgage book are worth at least 90 per cent of the property value they are secured against.

More

ON THIS STORY

By contrast, up to 12 per cent of loans provided byRoyal Bank of Scotland and Santander have a similarly high loan to value, while Nationwide, Barclays and HSBC have a smaller proportion of such risky loans.

The danger of these kinds of loans is that home buyers who make insignificant deposits are considered more likely to fall into arrears. High loan-to-value ratios also pose the risk of bigger losses if borrowers default.

Previous analysis from Standard & Poor’s, the credit rating agency, found that a borrower with a 10 per cent deposit was roughly twice as likely to fall into arrears as one putting down 30 to 40 per cent.

In total, 60 per cent of Lloyds’ secured debt book – which includes mortgages to individuals and businesses – has a loan to value deemed high or very high by the Bank of England, compared with 38 per cent for RBS, 33 per cent for Santander, and just 6 per cent for HSBC.

About 13 per cent of Lloyds’ £340bn mortgage book – £45bn of loans – exceed the value of the property they are secured upon. The actual number of borrowers in negative equity, where their property is worth less than their loan, is much smaller, at about 5 per cent. The figures show how vulnerable Lloyds is to a further souring of the UK economy, particularly another fall in house prices.

They also illustrate the challenges faced by António Horta-Osório, the new chief executive, who will present his initial strategic review to investors this week. Analysts said the concern was that a riskier loan book would push up funding costs for the bank just as it is attempting to boost returns.

“This increases the worry about the quality of Lloyds’ assets and the potential of loan losses to come,” said Ronit Ghose, an analyst at Citigroup.

Lloyds emphasised that negative equity only became a real concern for borrowers if they needed to move house and said it had a range of mortgage products to assist these customers.

It expected the loan-to-value position to be stable, although it forecasts a 2 per cent fall in house prices this year, as it believes they will rise by the same amount in 2012.

Analysts estimate that as much as three-quarters of Lloyds’ risky mortgage book was inherited from HBOS, which was one of the most aggressive lenders during the property boom.


2011年6月21日 星期二

6月20日,周一。上星期五,德國總理默克爾與法國總統薩爾科齊拍拍膊頭握握手,市場滿以為希臘「講掂數」,煲雖然遲早要爆,惟不在今天,美股周五升住嚟收。

老畢上周講過,國內政局愈亂,希臘與歐盟周旋的空間便愈大,總理帕潘德里歐以退為進,改組內閣威脅辭職雙管齊下,既做給反對派看,亦覷準德法不敢「瓷器撼缸瓦」,任由希臘失救,違約潮拖垮整個歐洲金融體系。

直至上周五,老畢仍認為帕潘德里歐這招見效。然而,德法亦非省油的燈,此例一開,歐盟日後豈非有求必應,得不斷向希臘供應「免費午餐」?不要忘記,德法手上有「援助」(aids)這張皇牌,可以用來反制雅典,歐盟豈有任由對方挾內亂得其所哉之理?如此這般,德法首腦握過手拍過膊頭,人人以為援希塵埃落定,歐盟卻突來一記反擊。要錢?可以,但得付出代價。就這樣,原定7月發放的120億歐羅撥款,一半hold住,畀唔畀足,要睇希臘減開支售資產削財赤做得夠不夠。

政治博弈結果難料

希臘資不抵債,實際上早已破產,歐盟和IMF千億歐羅千億歐羅地「掟」出去,填完一個氹又一個氹,說什麼也不容該國自生自滅,點解?

希臘(不用說葡萄牙、西班牙)倒下,不少揸重歐豬國債的銀行就要「陪葬」。然而,正如雷鼎鳴教授昨天在其專欄所言,要從根本上改變福利優厚國家的社會制度,促使過慣休閒生活工作意欲偏低的人民由豐入儉,十年八載恐亦難以為功。希臘當下水浸眼眉,奢求治本不切實際,退而求其次「放水」治標,能否成事亦要看國內外連串政治博弈的結果,第一道關卡是本文見報日希臘國會對政府的信任投票,其結果若非市場所願見,帕潘德里歐下台,勢必為國際社會二度救希增添莫大變數。

在民主國家,政客權力來自選票,當選民意願與市場意願相違背時,政客往往會作出在市場眼中「不理性」的決定,政治博弈結果因此十分難料。希臘政府信任投票開大開細,老畢無意亂猜。然而,近日市場尤其銀行同業拆息出現的變化,似在發出重要訊息,投資者必須留神。

先看資金成本指標。從【圖1】可見,三個月倫敦銀行同業拆息(LIBOR)與聯邦基金利率三個月平均息差(LIBOR-OIS spread),2008年金融危機期間一度逼近200基點,目前離「海嘯價」仍甚遠,跟去年歐債危機相比亦大有距離。再看【圖2】,LIBOR-OIS息差今年以來升得最急是3月日本天災核洩期間,之後隨市場焦點離開福島而大幅回落。不過,近日此指標又見抽升,目前已重返「福島價」,意味希臘違約風險已促使銀行不敢輕信同業,於交易對手的償付能力戒心大增。

同業「安全至上」

英國多份報章周末報道,港人熟悉的渣打銀行,近月在同業市場抽走了數以10億英鎊計的資金,過去數周更大削對歐羅區銀行的借貸,收縮幅度達三分之二,意味渣打不願在無抵押的短期同業市場承受風險。跟渣打一樣「安全至上」的金融機構,據說還有巴克萊等英資大行。這些財政相對健全的銀行,對法國等持有大量「歐豬」國債的區內銀行疑心尤重,巴克萊近期就大幅縮減在同業市場中對西班牙和意大利銀行的拆借業務。

所謂一葉知秋,同業間互不信任,有錢不借,此情此景,大家可有似曾相識之感?博反彈,還是留待心口掛住個「勇」字的諸君一試身手吧。

5月以來,環球股市在risk off潮下大幅調整,美股上周雖結束「六連跌」,惟弱勢未改。不過,跟其他市場相比,美股已算硬淨。

計計數,以本幣為準,標普500指數年初至今上升0.9%,表現優於德國以外的所有G7成員;與金磚四國相比,美股全勝。

然而,計入美元貶值因素,美股回報要打個折扣。即使如此,標普500指數仍然跑贏所有金磚四國股市,只是計入滙率變化後,美股跑贏英國、加拿大和日本,卻輸給法德意三個G7成員國【圖3】。

放大圖片


放大圖片

2010年10月13日 星期三

Asia and Brazil funds catch up

Asian and Latin American cities are catching up with London and New York as locations for the world’s biggest hedge funds.

São Paulo and Rio de Janeiro between them are now home to five hedge fund managers each managing more than $1bn – compared with one 12 months ago, data due to be released on Wednesday will show.


The figures, to be published by Hedge Fund Intelligence, the industry’s biggest database, will underscore the extent to which hedge fund managers are keen to operate closest to the markets generating the biggest returns.Hong Kong and Singapore are now home to 15 billion-dollar fund managers, up from 10 at the beginning of the year.

New York remains in the top spot, home to 124 managers with more than $1bn each. It has slipped fractionally – the city accounts for 46 per cent of assets managed by billion-dollar managers, down from 47 per cent last year.

London, in spite of a spate of big fund closures, has seen its share of assets managed by billion-dollar managers increase, from 14.8 to 15.5 per cent.

The City’s share of the global hedge fund industry has doubled in the past decade but for the past few years its position has remained largely unchanged.

Fund managers say that investors’ growing interest in emerging markets is the main reason funds have moved to new bases. Investors also increasingly prefer to put money with fund managers that have an on-the-ground presence in the regions they trade.

As a result, Hong Kong is fast cementing a position as the industry’s next big centre. While the city is home to 10 fund managers running more than $1bn each, it also hosts a number of high-profile medium-sized funds likely to grow in the coming months.

Start-ups such as Janchor Partners – run by TCI’s former regional head, John Ho – are attracting significant interest. The fund has more than quadrupled in size to $200m in the past nine months.

Industry growth in Brazil is also expected to continue. Established US and UK hedge funds have earmarked the region for expansion.

London-based Brevan Howard, the world’s fourth-largest hedge fund, was recently revealed to be opening a new office in São Paulo, to be headed by the outgoing governor of Brazil’s central bank.

JPMorgan’s Highbridge, the world’s second-largest fund manager, is still in talks toacquire Brazil’s largest hedge fund, Gávea

2010年10月5日 星期二

陳家強赴英游說基金在港註冊

財經事務及庫務局局長陳家強今年11月16日將率領證監會和金管局往倫敦訪問,主要目的是吸引更多基金公司採用香港為產品註冊地,促進本港相關金融服務業的發展。

「目前的監管框架並無不妥,但倘若有更多基金產品在港註冊,從促進就業的角度,將鼓勵基金公司使用本港的相關合規服務(例如會計、稅務和法律等)。」陳家強昨天與傳媒午宴時說。

資產管理業務一向是本港國際金融中心的支柱之一。參考證監會2009至2010年的年報,本港的認可單位信託和互惠基金共一千九百六十八隻,總資產接近9300億美元,按來源地劃分,盧森堡和愛爾蘭分別達64.49%和21.16%,英國則有4.32%,而本港註冊的只有3.44%。

陳家強強調,此行並非到當地「搶生意」,希望增加本港監管框架對當地基金公司的吸引力,現在稅務和法規等方面的考慮,影響基金公司在那裏註冊其產品,不排除日後可能要更新《公司條例》的有關規則,惟目前未有詳細計劃。

市場人士:法制最大考慮

香港已經與十四個國家簽署全面避免雙重徵稅協定,包括愛爾蘭和英國。不過,有資本市場人士認為,本港的稅率偏低,不是阻礙基金公司成立本港註冊產品的原因。事實上,法制才是最大的考慮,一方面投資者已熟習盧森堡或愛爾蘭的法規;另一方面,不少機構投資者對一國兩制當中法制這一環沒有很大信心,因此,既然在其他國家註冊的基金也可以在港銷售,基金公司缺乏誘因改為在港註冊。

證監會行政總裁韋奕禮、金管局及金融界的代表將隨行,屆時與倫敦的監管機構、基金公司及企業見面。訪問團可能多停留一個歐洲城市,但至今還未落實,初步計劃明年將到約紐進行同類的訪問。

韋奕禮昨天出席一公開場合時表示,很多在港銷售的基金產品都由其他司法管轄區發行,故必須確保產品特徵和風險披露一致,方便投資者比較不同產品。他又指出,證監會已為產品資料概要(KFS)定立樣板,旨在增加透明度,並讓基金公司易於符合披露的要求。

2010年3月29日 星期一

“Evidence of QE’s effectiveness remains somewhat elusive”

That’s the verdict from Richard McGuire, Senior Fixed Income Strategist at RBC Capital Markets on the matter of the Bank of England’s latest lending and money supply figures — specifically its preferred measure of money supply: ‘lending excluding intermediate other financial corporations’.

As McGuire noted, the second estimate of the figure slipped back into negative territory in February. It fell 1 per cent, having grown 0.6 per cent on a three-month annualised basis in Jan, a figure which was revised down from 1.9 per cent.

BoE lending data, meanwhile, showed that UK mortgage approvals unexpectedly fell to a nine-month low in February, with lenders granting 47,094 loans to buy homes, compared with 48,099 in January.

Which led IHS Global Insight’s Howard Archer to conclude it might be too early for the Bank to say goodbye to QE for good:

Overall, the February data do little to ease concern over low money supply growth and bank lending to businesses. It is evident that ongoing very weak bank lending to companies continues to reflect both low demand for credit from businesses as well as restricted supply from the banks.

Following on from a still largely downbeat Bank of England’s March Trends in Lending survey, the ongoing weak February data maintains concern that ongoing tight credit conditions remain a serious obstacle to significant, sustainable recovery.

This keeps open the possibility that the Bank of England could revive Quantitative Easing, although we suspect that the MPC would prefer not to go down that route unless the economy shows serious signs of faltering over the next few months.

Related links:
Could UK money supply collapse post-QE?
- FT Alphaville
UK hits worst deflation on record
– HoweStreet
Allocating, multiplying, QE - FT Alphaville

2010年3月11日 星期四

Sterling: vampire squid really quite confident

…in the long term.

Amidst an analyst note on the difficulties of measuring fiscal policy impacts on exchange rates, Goldman has weighed in on the Great British Krona. Good news, sterling: the beatings will stop. Eventually.

From the note:

The general assumption is that if the UK election does result in a hung parliament, it will become difficult to enact the required legislation to bring the fiscal deficit down…

…Between now and then, the Pound may well remain hostage to developments in the polls and the tone of the election campaign, particularly on the fiscal front…

In addition, Sterling is still plagued by lacklustre activity data and a relatively dovish central bank. We do expect both of these factors to turn more bullish for the Pound further out but in the near term they may also weigh on Sterling. Taking these three factors together, we have revised our 3-month EUR/GBP view to 0.87 from 0.84.

However, we have not changed our 6- and 12-month forecasts, which stay at 0.84.

That’s due to Goldman’s ‘above-consensus’ growth forecast for the UK, which they see as plausible due to business survey data so far. How far above consensus, and how plausible? You decide:

At present, the hard data is weaker than the survey data says it should be. This is particularly true of the GDP data; however, some of the more frequent, monthly hard data still seems to be lagging somewhat. We continue to expect the hard data to catch up with the strength of the survey data and thus look for the Bank of England to change stance and hike rates in August. Specifically, we expect the UK economy to grow by 1.8% and 3.4% in 2010 and 2011, compared with 1.4% and 2.2% from the consensus.

This underpins our more hawkish view of rates, where we expect the Bank of England to hike rates by 300bp vs market expectations of 250bp. The recent change in tone from the Riksbank and the subsequent appreciation of the SEK is a good template for the potential dynamics of the Pound.

Great British Krona, indeed. That would be the Swedish krona as a model for sterling – not the Icelandic krona. Fortunately.

Even so, Sweden is an intriguing model, to say the least. While the Riksbank has been getting ready to end ‘crisis interest rates’, the Swedish economy tipped back into recession in the meantime – throwing monetary policy up in the air.

As a coda to all of this, do bear in mind that Goldman have also recently advised on trading ideas for a sterling slump in the short term. Wily one, that vampire squid.

Oh, and what did the Goldman note conclude overall? Fiscal policy ‘dominates as a key issue’ when it comes to currency valuation. Do remember that, Westminster.

Related links:
Goldman’s sterling-slump strategy – FT Alphaville
Scylla and Charybdis, sterling edition - FT Alphaville
The Great British Peso – FT Alphaville
‘If you really want a fiscal problem, look at the UK’ – FT Alphaville

2010年1月5日 星期二

Consolidating the US, UK gov’t bond sell-off

With the holiday season finally over, it’s probably a good time to contemplate the period’s more excessive and illiquid market moves. Among them the rather sudden and acute sell-off in US and UK government bonds. Was it rational?

As the following charts depict, British government bonds ended 2009 with their worst monthly performance since the start of the year.

US Treasury notes, the 10-year yields of which were approaching their highest level since June on Monday, registered the worst sovereign debt performance of 2009 according to Bloomberg:

US 10-year Treasuries - Bloomberg

10-year Gilts - Bloomberg

As far as the UK is concerned, even upbeat manufacturing and lending data was unable to reverse the sell-off in any decisive fashion on Monday. As Reuters reported:

LONDON, Jan 4 (Reuters) – British gilt prices were little changed on Monday despite upbeat manufacturing and lending data as investors assessed the sustainability of sharp price falls during thin trading over the Christmas period. At 1247 GMT the March long gilt future was flat at 114.45 in thin trade on the first trading day of 2010, when most dealers were back after two weeks of thin markets due to the Christmas and New Year holidays.

Meanwhile, Pacific Investment Management, aka bond-fund Pimco, fuelled further jitters after announcing it was planning to cut its holdings of US and UK debt due to the countries’ record borrowing levels.

According to Bloomberg:

Pimco is “more cautious” on corporate bonds and holds fewer mortgage-backed securities than the percentages in the benchmarks it uses to gauge performance, wrote Paul McCulley, a portfolio manager and member of the investment committee, in his 2010 outlook.

The company is also underweight Treasury Inflation Protected Securities, according to the report on Newport Beach, California-based Pimco’s Web site. “This all leaves us with portfolios that appear, more than at other times, to be hugging the benchmarks with no bold positioning,” McCulley wrote. “We’re making a very active decision to run light on risk.”

Which presumably suggests the bond sell-off was justifiable after all?

Related links:
After the decade of debt: A course to chart
- FT
Our wall of gilts is casting a long shadow over 2010
- FT

2009年12月22日 星期二

Why market sentiment has no credibility

By Robert Skidelsky
Published: December 22 2009 20:30 Last updated: December 22 2009 20:30

It is not surprising that Britain’s largest economic downturn since the war should have seen the largest ever peacetime government budget deficit. By the end of this year Britain’s output will have fallen by about 5 per cent since the crisis started; in the same period the budget deficit will have risen by between 5 per cent and 8 per cent of output. Arithmetic so simple that even a child can understand it: smaller output, smaller revenues, larger deficit. And the corollary: larger output, larger revenues, smaller deficit.
The deficit for 2009-10 is projected to be £178bn (€200bn, $287bn), about 11 per cent of gross domestic product. There is some dispute as to how much of this is “structural” and how much “cyclical”. The “structural” deficit is the gap between government revenue and spending that will have to be closed by higher taxes or lower spending. The “cyclical” deficit is the gap that will automatically disappear when the economy has recovered. Those who say the downturn has added 8 per cent rather than 5 per cent to the deficit argue the recovered UK economy will be smaller than the pre-recession one, hence the recovery will leave a gap of £132bn rather than £100bn. Whatever the right number, no one doubts that there will remain a sizeable fiscal problem, even after the downturn has been reversed.
But why has the financial press been almost unanimous in condemning the modest pre-Budget measures announced by Alistair Darling, chancellor of the exchequer, to protect total spending in the face of a massive collapse of private demand? Why are the markets howling for “fiscal consolidation” now – ie cutting fiscal support to the economy immediately – when it has plainly not yet recovered?
To understand “market sentiment”, one has to go back to two ideas in the minds of most financial analysts which almost unconsciously shape their arguments. The first is the belief that economies are always at full employment. The second is the belief that even if they are not (obviously contradicting the first), they very soon would be if only governments would stop bailing them out.
The first is perhaps the most pervasive. It takes the form of denying that there is an output gap. That is, at all points in time output is no more or less than what the economy is able to produce. If this is so, government attempts to close an imaginary output gap by running a deficit will either take money better spent by the private sector or be inflationary. (Output-gap deniers always see the microbe of inflation in the air.) Either way deficits are bad, which is why “fiscal consolidation” needs to happen immediately. In the early days of the crisis this deep theoretical commitment to the existence of continuous full employment was temporarily overcome by common sense. But as the fear of apocalypse receded normal intellectual service was resumed.
The more cautious version of “output gap denial” is the view that the pre-crisis level of output was the result of bank-financed debt, and that much of it went for good with the credit crunch. Public finances cannot rely on a recovery of output to produce a stream of revenue to reduce the deficit because – wait for it – there is little or no output to be recovered.
Even the normally sober Martin Wolf has fallen for this line (FT, December 16 2009). The pre-crisis UK economy, he says, was a “bubble economy”. The bubble made UK output seem larger than it actually was! This is old-fashioned Puritanism: the boom was the illusion, the slump is the return of reality. However, experience of past recessions suggests that, once the corner is turned, output recovers vigorously from slump conditions (as do prices). Between 1933 and 1937 the UK economy expanded by 4 per cent a year, much higher than its “trend” rate of growth. Yet in 1931 orthodox economists were denying there was an output gap at the bottom of the greatest depression in history.
The second theoretical commitment of most financial analysts is that economies, if disturbed, revert quickly back to full employment if not further deranged by government actions. Thus contrary to the commonsense view that massive government intervention last autumn stopped the slide down to another Great Depression, the new conservative commentators (having got their breath and confidence back!) now argue that ill-conceived government measures have stopped, or are hindering, the natural recovery mechanisms.
For example, it is argued that massive government borrowing is keeping yields higher than they would otherwise be. Thus government efforts to stimulate spending have the effect only of retarding a natural fall in the rate of interest. If its borrowing is not rapidly reduced there will be a “gilt strike” – investors will demand higher and higher prices for holding government paper. Faced with the evidence that, despite increased government borrowing, gilt yields have been at a historic low, the critics say that this is only because the gilts are being bought by the Bank of England. Once the Bank stops buying government debt, interest rates will shoot up.
A parallel argument is that the expansion of the fiscal deficit is preventing a natural fall in the exchange rate sufficient to boost exports. The tortuous logic seems to be that “fiscal consolidation” will cause the rate of interest to fall and the fall in interest rates will cause the exchange rate to fall, thus increasing the demand for British exports. It is often alleged that something like this happened in 1931 when Britain left the gold standard for the last time.
Empirical evidence supporting the view that cutting the deficit causes the exchange rate to fall is very thin. A 1997 study by the International Monetary Fund showed that in only 14 out of 74 studied instances did fiscal consolidation promote a recovery via a fall in the exchange rate. In all the other cases fiscal policy either had no discernible exchange rate effect or it was the expansion of the deficit that caused the exchange rate to fall.
This only confirms what common sense and elementary Keynesian theory would lead one to expect. In a slump there is no natural tendency for the rate of interest to fall, because people’s desire to hoard money is increasing. So printing enough money to “satisfy the hoarder” is the only way of getting interest rates or the exchange-rate down.
But, of course, there is always “market sentiment” to fall back on. The government must cut its spending now, because this is what “the markets” expect. These are the same markets that so wounded the banking system that it had to be rescued by the taxpayer. They are now demanding fiscal consolidation as the price of their continued support for governments whose fiscal troubles they have largely caused.
Why on earth should we take this market sentiment any more seriously than that which led to the great debauch of 2007? Markets, it is sometimes said, may not know what they are talking about, but governments have no choice but to do what they tell them. This is unacceptable. The duty of governments is to govern in the best interests of the people who elected them not of the City of London. If that means calling the bankers’ bluff, so be it.

Lord Skidelsky is emeritus professor of political economy at the University of Warwick. His latest book Keynes: The Return of the Master was published in September

2009年12月21日 星期一

London as a financial centre - Foul-weather friends

Dec 17th 2009 HONG KONG, LONDON AND NEW YORKFrom The Economist print edition
How London risks losing its global appeal
Illustration by S. Kambayashi


AT THE start of the 1960s London’s status as a financial centre was in gentle decline, reflecting Britain’s waning importance in the global economy. Then the American government helpfully imposed Regulation Q and the Interest Equalisation Tax, two measures that encouraged investors to hold a lot of their dollars offshore. London became the centre of the so-called Euromarket, attracting more international banks than New York.
Despite its terrible weather and creaking transport infrastructure, London has continued to punch above Britain’s economic weight as a financial centre. The city built up critical mass in legal, accounting and fund-management expertise, and big American investment banks such as Goldman Sachs steadily increased their presence. London is not just Europe’s dominant financial hub (see chart). Before the credit crunch, talk that London would replace New York as the world’s financial centre was commonplace.
That claim sounds rather hollow now, thanks to a change in the political and regulatory climate. “London’s position as a financial centre is now threatened,” says Robin Bowie of Dexion Capital, which runs a listed fund-of-hedge-funds group. A special levy on bankers’ bonuses announced earlier this month has come on top of a forthcoming 50% tax rate on high earners, a charge on the worldwide earnings of expats living in Britain (also known as “non-doms”), pension rules that create marginal tax rates of over 100% and some unfriendly words from Adair Turner, the head of Britain’s financial regulator.
A poll of Bloomberg subscribers in October found that Britain had dropped behind Singapore into third place as the city most likely to be the best financial hub two years from now. A survey of executives this month by Eversheds, a law firm, found that Shanghai could overtake London within the next ten years.
To those affected it is the arbitrary nature of the tax changes that has them rattled. “There has always been a belief that Britain gets it,” says Simon Ruddick of Albourne Partners, a hedge-fund consultancy. “By ‘it’ I mean the fact that any tax gathered from the nomadic nom-doms, itinerant hedge-fund managers and overpaid bankers is all fiscal manna from heaven. Now that this truth has been un-learned, there is the real fear and strong expectation that it cannot be relearned.”
So far, Heathrow has not been packed with financiers fleeing the country (if staff at British Airways and Eurostar go on strike, they may find it hard to leave). But it takes time for people to adjust their plans. A survey of financial analysts in September by the CFA Institute found that 20% expected to leave Britain over the next year.
British banks report that since the bonus tax was announced, overseas rivals have launched aggressive attempts to poach staff away, using lower taxes as a lure. One French-born but London-based entrepreneur says he has a letter on his desk from the French government, offering a cap on his taxes if he brings his business back home. He has not taken up the offer but thinks it is “red alert” time for London, which has a large base of French expatriates. Tullett Prebon, a brokerage, is offering its staff the chance to relocate out of Britain, noting that many had expressed concern about the “increased uncertainty of the future tax regime”.
Hedge funds, always the most mobile of firms, are likely to be in the vanguard of any exodus. BlueCrest Capital Management, a leading British hedge-fund group, is establishing a Geneva office. Odey Asset Management, another hedge-fund titan, says it is in the process of establishing a Swiss operation in order to give itself some options, although it is unlikely that the whole operation would leave Britain. “Taxation is no longer being organised on the basis of what maximises revenue or creates the best set of incentives,” says Nick Carn, an Odey partner.
Driving the wealthy abroad may satisfy a political need for vengeance but could harm taxpayers in the end. The British government estimates that the top 1% of all taxpayers (many of whom work in finance or related industries) will pay 24.1% of all income-tax revenues in 2009-10, with the top 5% paying 43% of the total. It is likely that such taxpayers also pay a big proportion of stamp duty, capital-gains tax and inheritance tax. In the decade before the crisis, financial companies were paying 20-27% of all corporation-tax receipts.
A big decline in tax revenues would come not from the departure of a few hedge-fund managers, but from the loss of a big bank. There is no sign of this yet. The chief executive of HSBC is moving his main office to Hong Kong in February, but this decision is for “strategic reasons” and involves only 12-15 people. The bank says there are “no current plans” to move the headquarters of the overall group. But it may be wrong to assume that no big bank would leave Britain.
In a speech on December 14th Bob Diamond, president of Barclays, said it was worrisome that Britain is “looking inward” and added that the bonus tax “is separate from what we agreed” at the G20, where a code was drawn up to push banks into paying bonuses over much longer periods, to discourage short-term risk-taking.

For every loser
If there were an exodus from London, where might the financiers go? The grass may not necessarily be greener on the other side of the Atlantic. Congress is still pushing ahead with reform of the finance industry—the House of Representatives passed its bill on December 11th. Anger at Wall Street bonuses is widespread. “I did not run for office to be helping out a bunch of fat-cat bankers on Wall Street,” said Barack Obama on December 13th. Kenneth Feinberg, the administration’s pay tsar, has imposed restrictions on firms that have taken lots of government cash. Others are having to show more self-restraint: Goldman Sachs has promised to pay bonuses to its top 30 employees purely in shares.
Asia will naturally become more important as a financial centre, given its economic power and its role as the provider of global savings. Much of that money is directed at other emerging markets and need not flow through London or New York. There is no big city in Asia that does not have at least some aspiration to become a financial hub. Stymied by a small home market, Kuala Lumpur dreams of being a Mecca for Islamic finance. Seoul and Tokyo say they want to become regional financial centres; Mumbai and Shanghai say they want to become global ones. Hong Kong and Singapore, without size, money or resources, have shown what is possible: they are crawling with international fund managers and bankers, plus all the accoutrements of accountants and lawyers.
The success of these last two places shows how important a welcoming regulatory regime can be. It also helps if near-neighbours are far less welcoming. London has benefited from being perceived as an outcrop of “Anglo-Saxon” capitalism within the more dirigiste European Union. This difference has blurred. France has said that it will follow Britain’s lead in imposing a bonus tax, while Greece has promised a 90% levy (Athens is not renowned as a global financial hub). The heads of Germany’s biggest banks and insurers have agreed to implement G20 rules on bonus limits this year, ahead of the official 2010 implementation elsewhere, in what seemed a clear move to head off political pressure for a windfall tax like Britain’s. Earlier this year Josef Ackermann, the head of Deutsche Bank, warned that unilateral pay limits would leave it unable to attract good staff. Outside the EU, Switzerland is an obvious threat.
Some of the complaints of London’s financiers are special pleading. It is easier to threaten to leave the country than actually to do so. But those threats should not be taken lightly. The city’s status as a financial centre is not a God-given right.

Banks and the FSR


The Bank of England’s Financial Stability Report (FSR) was released overnight and the focus, as one would expect, is on capital and liquidity.

But Jonathan Pierce, Credit Suisse’s banking analyst, says the most interesting thing is the suggestion (repeated several times in the 74-page report) that banks should use stable markets to issue more, non-guaranteed wholesale funding and to raise capital externally.

From the FSR:

Banks should take advantage of favourable market conditions.

Despite inevitable short-term costs, there is a strong case for banks acting now to improve balance sheet positions while conditions are favourable. Retaining a higher share of current buoyant earnings could significantly increase banks’ resilience and ability to lend. If discretionary distributions had been 20% lower per year between 2000 and 2008, banks would have generated around £75 billion of additional capital — more than provided by the public sector during the crisis.

It is also an opportune time for banks to raise capital externally, extend the maturity of their funding, and develop and implement plans for refinancing substantial sums as official sector support is withdrawn.

Taking advantage of current favourable conditions would help to repair balance sheets and thereby insure banks against future adverse developments. Given their balance sheet vulnerabilities, banks remain exposed to any future deterioration in macroeconomic and market conditions, which could substantially raise the cost of funding and capital raising in the future.

Coming hot on the heels of Thursday’s report from the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, this means the capital debate will continue, says Pierce, who has also done some quick maths on the Basel III consultation paper.

Applying the new Basel definitions, he thinks Barclays’ equity Tier 1 capital could fall by 300 basis points, Lloyds by 360bps and RBS 450bps.

Which leads Pierce to conclude:

Capital and liquidity remain big challenges and shareholders are likely to be subordinated in the interests of stability for quite some time, in our view. Indeed, we think that the various papers from the FSA, BIS and BOE in recent weeks support our view that, structurally, the UK banks will struggle to generate ROTE much above 10-12% in the medium term.

Small wonder then, that UK banks stocks are under pressure this morning.

—–

Other highlights from the FSR:

  • Banks will face higher capital requirements on trading assets and securitisations from 2011 — of around £33bn for financial institutions in the United Kingdom.
  • Over the next five years, UK banks also need to refinance over £1 trillion of wholesale funding, including funding that has been supported by the public sector.
  • Improving balance sheet structures may be costly. In retail markets, competition for funding has raised retail bond rates to around 200 basis points above risk-free rates, compared with a spread below zero in 2005. And, in wholesale markets, longer-term interest rates are well above short-term rates. Based on those rates, the cost to the industry of increasing the maturity of funding, while replacing Special Liquidity Scheme (SLS) and Credit Guarantee Scheme (CGS) support and acquiring low-yielding assets to meet regulatory requirements, could be significant.
  • Outstanding loans to the commercial property sector were over £250bn at end-September 2009, nearly six times their level a decade earlier. The major UK banks have lent around £200bn to the sector and have additional contingent exposures of over £30bn in the form of undrawn credit facilities. In addition, the largest UK banks have gross exposures of over £18bn to securities backed by domestic and foreign commercial real estate loans.
  • In the United Kingdom, past falls in commercial property prices have raised average loan to value (LTV) ratios above 100 per cent, according to industry estimates. Around £160bn of loans are scheduled to be refinanced between 2009 and 2013

Related links:
Bank calls City’s bluff on regulation – FT
Digesting the Basel reforms – FT Alphaville
Strengthening the resilience of the banking sector – BIS
International framework for liquidity risk measurement, standards and monitoring
– BIS

All hail the Basel banking regime change

For it is — after much speculation and hand-wringing — here.

And here’s the summary of what the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, which sets the supervisory standards for many of the world’s banks, is suggesting to strengthen the sector:

First, the quality, consistency, and transparency of the capital base will be raised. This will ensure that large, internationally active banks are in a better position to absorb losses on both a going concern and gone concern basis. For example, under the current Basel Committee standard, banks could hold as little as 2% common equity to risk-based assets, before the application of key regulatory adjustments.

Second, the risk coverage of the capital framework will be strengthened. In addition to the trading book and securitisation reforms announced in July 2009, the Committee is proposing to strengthen the capital requirements for counterparty credit risk exposures arising from derivatives, repos, and securities financing activities. These enhancements will strengthen the resilience of individual banking institutions and reduce the risk that shocks are transmitted from one institution to the next through the derivatives and financing channel. The strengthened counterparty capital requirements also will increase incentives to move OTC derivative exposures to central counterparties and exchanges.

Third, the Committee will introduce a leverage ratio as a supplementary measure to the Basel II risk-based framework with a view to migrating to a Pillar 1 treatment based on appropriate review and calibration. This will help contain the build up of excessive leverage in the banking system, introduce additional safeguards against attempts to game the risk based requirements, and help address model risk. To ensure comparability, the details of the leverage ratio will be harmonised internationally, fully adjusting for any remaining differences in accounting. The ratio will be calibrated so that it serves as a credible supplementary measure to the riskbased requirements, taking into account the forthcoming changes to the Basel II framework.

Fourth, the Committee is introducing a series of measures to promote the build up of capital buffers in good times that can be drawn upon in periods of stress. A countercyclical capital framework will contribute to a more stable banking system, which will help dampen, instead of amplify, economic and financial shocks. In addition, the Committee is promoting more forward looking provisioning based on expected losses, which captures actual losses more transparently and is also less procyclical than the current “incurred loss” provisioning model.

Fifth, the Committee is introducing a global minimum liquidity standard for internationally active banks that includes a 30-day liquidity coverage ratio requirement underpinned by a longer-term structural liquidity ratio. The framework also includes a common set of monitoring metrics to assist supervisors in identifying and analysing liquidity risk trends at both the bank and system wide level. These standards and monitoring metrics complement the Committee’s Principles for Sound Liquidity Risk Management and Supervision issued in September 2008.

The full Basel paper is available here, and the liquidity supplement is here.

And the market reaction for selected banks:


Related links:
Bank capital rules face overhaul – FT
A Basel breather heard ’round the world – FT Alphaville
A Basel round-up for bonus-bugged bankers – FT Alphaville
Counting the costs of more bank capital – FT Alphaville

Digesting the Basel reforms

The latest Basel proposals for the banking sector were released on Thursday, and they are not going down well.

Here’s a snap summary from the banks team at Credit Suisse:

The Basel Committee has published its latest thoughts on capital and liquidity. We are still digesting the main implications of this, but at first read it looks pretty punitive on the sector. In particular, the new definitions of common equity tier 1 appear to take a very hardline with the majority of deferred tax assets, insurance equity capital, excess expected losses, unrealised debt losses, minority interests and pension fund liabilities being deducted. Other supervisory deductions will get a 1250% risk weight on these proposals. The calculation of counterparty credit risk also seems to be changing markedly. The liquidity document seems less surprising with the broad thrust being an increase in Government bond holdings and a reduction in short-term wholesale funding which we have written about extensively before.

Overall, we believe this is negative for the European banks sector. Timeline for implementation isn’t until 2012, with grandfathering arrangements thereafter, but the market is likely to look through this and penalise banks which rely heavily on DTA, pension fund add backs, and financial subsidiary capital in our view.

For individual banks, we need to do more work, but our first read is that UK banks, in particular LBG and RBS look substantially exposed (see our research pre-empting this two weeks ago). But this will affect most European banks as well. For example, the French banks have 6-22% of equity tier 1 capital from minorities. Consider also that Credit Agricole and Natixis are potentially exposed due to the listed entity owning 20-25% of their own retail networks with the associated deduction 50% from tier 1 and tier 2 – the rules might not apply here but could create uncertainties until decisions are made in 2010. Another example is Dexia with an equity tier one ratio at 10.8% but below 5% if the €8.8bn of unrealised negative AFS currently not deducted is applied to tier 1. Other regions, like Scandinavia and Italy are arguably less exposed given tier 1 definitions are already prudently struck.

Of course, these are still proposals and there’s a lot of detail still to emerge. There might also be national discretions, although the aim of this in part seems to be to remove those. One need only look at the Australian banks, several of which would report equity tier 1 ratios 200bps higher were they to adopt UK FSA standards. But generally speaking, the definitions are tightening up for all. Of course, the BIS might apply relatively low equity tier 1 minima, in line with tighter definitions. The question then is whether the market would accept lower headline numbers, or still push for relatively high (e.g. 8-10%) ratios on the new definitions. At the very least, the BIS’ starting point seems to be a relatively hardline approach to new capital and liquidity definitions – and hence we would view this negatively for the sector as a whole.

The real sticking point here seems to be changes to the definition of Tier 1 equity. Minority interests no longer apply, unrealised losses (and gains) must be taken into account, the use of deferred tax assets is largely ruled out and there are stringent new rules proposed for the related treatment of pension fund deficits. In short, banks’ core equity is going to have to get a lot purer.

Also, at the Tier 2 level, it looks like banks will be kissing goodbye to the upper and lower divisions.

There are some very complex changes to the treatment of counterparty risk, including the charming concept of “wrong way” risk, and also alterations to calculations like the probability of default, which in future will include the important caveat: in a downturn.

Meanwhile, on the liquidity front, the proposed framework here is broadly as expected, with banks being required to hold significantly more government bonds on their books.

Here’s some more from Credit Suisse:

1. Liquidity coverage ratio. This new regulatory ratio aims to ensure adequate liquidity in the event of another market disclocation. It is meant to require a bank to maintain an adequate level of “unencumbered, high quality assets that can be converted into cash to meet its liquidity needs for a 30 day time horizon under an acute liquidity stress scenario”. The ratio is defined as:

· (stock of high quality liquid assets) / (net cash outflows over a 30 day time period), with a minimum of 100%.

With high quality liquid assets including Government bonds and covered bonds. This isn’t a major surprise and is effectively a similar definition to central bank eligible collateral pre-crisis. More surprising though is the regulator’s assessment of an extreme stress scenario:

· 7.5% of “stable” retail and small business deposits go in the first 30 days;
· 15% of “less stable”deposits, high net worth (uninsured) deposits and internet deposits;
· 25% of wholesale funding with a maturity of less than 30 days supplied by large corporate customers as part of an operational payments services float;
· 75% of wholesale funding < 30 days from large corporate customers other than as part of payment systems float;
· 100% of interbank funding with a maturity of less than 30 days.

2. Net stable funding ratio. This new regulatory ratio aims to “promote more medium and long-term funding of the assets and activities of banking organisations”. It is defined as:

· (available amount of stable funding) / (required amount of stable funding) with a minimum of 100%

The numerator of this ratio is roughly equivalent to “core funding”, as defined in the Reserve Bank of New Zealand regulations and in our recent note “More important than Tier One?”, 27 November. It is calculated using a weighting schedule as below:

· 100% of total tier 1 and tier 2 capital and preferred stock
· 100% of liabilities with a contractual maturity >1yr
· 85% of “stable” retail and small business deposits with maturity <1yr
· 70% of “less stable” retail and small business with maturity <1yr
· 50% of large corporate deposits with maturity <1>

plus

· 10% of all undrawn committed credit lines and overdraft facilities
· And a percentage of guarantees, uncommitted credit lines, letters of credit, potential money market mutual fund repurchase obligations etc, at local regulator’s discretion.

The denominator is calculated as a weighted sum of the asset side of the balance sheet:

· 0% weighting – cash, securities with a remaining maturity <1yr, interbank loans with a maturity <1 yr, securities held with an offsetting reverse repo
· 5% weighting – unpledged high-quality liquid securities (similar definition to central bank eligible collateral)
· 20% weighting – corporate bonds and covered bonds with a proven record of liquidity (ie, no major increases in repo haircut in the last 10 years)
· 50% weighting – other corporate bonds, gold, equities, loans to corporates with a maturity less than one year
· 85% weighting – retail loans with a maturity less than one year
· 100% weighting – all loans with maturity > one year, all other assets

All in all, the view seems to be that this is a tad more aggressive than forecast. According to back of an envelope calculations by Credit Suisse, the European banking sector as a whole will have an aggregate funding requirement of €1,100bn.

Credit Suisse says that is broadly as expected, but it still sounds like an awfully large amount of money.

Related links:
Bank capital rules face overhaul
– FT
Strengthening the resilience of the banking sector
– BIS
International framework for liquidity risk measurement, standards and monitoring
– BIS

2009年12月16日 星期三

Labour's pre-budget report - Drawing up the battle lines

Dec 10th 2009From The Economist print edition
The chancellor’s fiscal statement was all about politics

A YEAR ago, when Alistair Darling presented his pre-budget report, the chancellor of the exchequer unveiled an astonishing deterioration in the public finances. That got even worse in his spring budget. Judged by those titanic standards, the pre-budget report on December 9th was a tame affair. But it still mattered for what it revealed about the government’s priorities in dealing with a still-floundering economy and Britain’s huge budget deficit. Above all, it outlined the case Labour will put to voters at the election due by June.
Mr Darling had to own up to a much bigger contraction in the economy this year than he expected at the time of the budget. The Treasury thinks GDP will shrink by 4.75% in 2009, whereas in April it was forecasting a fall of 3.5%. But it still expects the economy to expand by about 1.25% in 2010, and indeed to emerge from recession in the final quarter of this year. The chancellor is sticking to his prediction of 3.5% growth in 2011, which was criticised as over-optimistic this spring, and thinks it will carry on in 2012.

One of the main dividing lines between the Labour government and its main Conservative opposition is over when fiscal retrenchment should begin. Mr Darling argued in effect that the recovery was safer in Labour’s hands because he would delay the strong medicine needed to right the deficit until 2011, when the patient would be ready to take it. He made much of various measures to support businesses in the early stages of the upturn.
For once Mr Darling was spared the embarrassment of having to unveil yet another massive deterioration in the borrowing numbers—just as well given how terrible they already were. A year ago he said that the deficit in 2009-10 would soar from the £38 billion ($62 billion) stated in the 2008 budget to £118 billion. That was revised up again in April 2009 to an even more breathtaking £175 billion. But this week the chancellor raised that by a mere bagatelle, to £178 billion, equal to 12.6% of GDP.
Mr Darling has also stuck broadly to his leisurely plan for bringing the public finances back into balance, first set out a year ago and then revised in April. As before, the chancellor expects the deficit to fall to 5.5% of GDP by 2013-14 (see chart). And as before, he postpones half the pain to the next parliament but one: not until 2017-18 is the current budget (which excludes net investment) back in balance.
Another dividing line that Labour is keen to draw has to do with readiness to raise taxes on the better-off. The chancellor continued his attack on very high earners, by reducing further the tax relief available to them on their pension contributions and unveiling a one-off tax on bank bonuses, which may reap £550m this year. He will also freeze in 2012-13 the threshold, currently almost £44,000 of earnings, at which middle-income folk become liable to pay income tax at 40%. And, in a dig at the Tories, who are committed to raising the tax-free limit for inheritance tax to £1m, the chancellor said he would freeze the current threshold at £325,000 next year.
Unfortunately for Mr Darling, the big money is in the taxes paid by the many rather than the few. As well as confirming his plan to end the temporary reduction in VAT at the start of 2010, the chancellor has turned again to his favourite levy, national-insurance contributions. A year ago he said he intended raising the rates by half a percentage point in 2011-12; now he is making that a full percentage point. The chancellor has, however, sought to sweeten the pill for lower earners (with income below £20,000) by raising the point at which people start to pay these contributions.
Raising this tax will not go down well but it was vital to enable Mr Darling to make his most important political point of all: that Labour is the guardian of crucial public services. The extra revenue will pay for most of an additional £7.7 billion of spending in 2011-12 and £6.9 billion in 2012-13. Some other improvements in the budgetary arithmetic meant that Mr Darling could unveil this extra expenditure without changing his overall forecasts for borrowing for those years.
That enabled the chancellor to make a vital pledge—that the “front-line” services that people care about will be safe under Labour, not just next year but in the following two. The pre-budget report said that in real terms 95% of the NHS budget would be shielded from cuts in 2011-12 and 2012-13, and everyday spending on schools would rise by 0.7% a year. The number of police officers would also be left intact.
Mr Darling moved a step closer to spelling out the painful clampdown on public spending that lies ahead by saying he would cap pay increases in the public sector in those two years at 1%. He also promised reforms to public-service pensions that would save £1 billion a year from 2012-13. And there was plenty of talk about vague new efficiencies that will yield sackloads of savings across the public sector.
Despite the tough rhetoric, the chancellor has taken a calculated risk in what his Tory opposite number, George Osborne, dubbed a pre-election report. The government’s plan to reduce the deficit is widely regarded as insufficient. Rather than use higher taxes to lower borrowing, Mr Darling has used them to cut spending by less. The deficit in 2013-14 could prove higher than the Treasury expects. John Hawksworth, an economist at PWC, an accountancy firm, thinks it is likely to be 6.9% of GDP then rather than 5.5%.
With an election so near, the pre-budget report was bound to be a holding operation. The real plan will come after the election, and it will involve real pain. That is the price of messing up the public finances as thoroughly as Labour has done.

Darling’s fiscal fiction

Posted by Neil Hume on Dec 10 09:45.

BNP Paribas’
Alan Clarke is not the only City economist seriously displeased with Wednesday’s pre-Budget report.
Citigroup’s Michael Saunders also has a few choice words for the chancellor, who he accuses of trying to create a fiscal fiction that the UK’s huge deficit can be resolved by taxing the ‘few and not the many’.
(Emphasis ours) The PBR appears to be aimed at reviving Labour’s core support rather than seriously tackling the UK’s medium-term fiscal problems. The PBR extends the “tax, borrow and spend” fiscal trend of recent years, with slight upward revisions to the deficit forecast for 09/10 and 10/11, further tax hikes on top income earners and slight rises in planned public spending in 10/11. Moreover, it does not produce credible and detailed plans to return the UK to a sustainable fiscal stance in coming years.
In our view the PBR seeks to create a fiscal fiction that the deficit can be resolved solely by tax hikes on a relatively small share of the population (’the few, not the many’) and without painful public spending cuts. The revenue forecasts again look over-optimistic, and there are no public spending plans after 2010/11 — only vague forecasts. The Chancellor pledged to protect spending on health, schools and the police, but gave no sign where the axe will fall. Given the record of recent years, this lack of clarity is likely to fuel scepticism whether the Chancellor really is committed to spending restraint.
Saunders fears the the fiction might work and deprive the Conservatives of an overall majority after the election.
And that poses very serious risks for the UK economy.Rather than produce a serious and credible fiscal consolidation plan, the Chancellor’s aim looks to be chiefly political: to reinforce Labour’s core vote and try to deprive the Conservatives of a majority in Parliament after the next election. The Conservatives need to be at least 10% ahead of Labour (roughly) to get a majority in Parliament (the required lead increases if the Lib Dems do well). Recent polls suggest that the Conservatives are indeed about 10% ahead of Labour, but polls also suggest that Labour’s core support is significantly higher than Labour’s current voting intentions (whereas the Conservatives’ voting intentions are well above their core support).
Thus, Labour’s political strategy look to be aimed at making the election tribal (hence the “class war” rhetoric); to avoid hurting their own core support (hence no early fiscal tightening); and to portray the Conservatives as a party that wants to cut public spending for ideological reasons (to detach floating voters from the Conservatives).
This approach seems to be working in political terms: three of the last five polls have pointed to a hung parliament. But, in market terms, it implies no preelection commitment to fiscal consolidation and a growing risk that there will be a hung parliament — which also could prevent early fiscal consolidation post-election as well.


Related links:
Darling starts to tighten the screw - FT
UK PBR - recipe for a downgrade? - FT Alphaville
Prevarication and Newspeak will not fix our finances - Willem Buiter / FT
A reality check for fiscal Pollyannas - John Kay / FT

2009年12月15日 星期二

Britain’s dismal choice: how to share the losses

By Martin Wolf
Published: December 15 2009 22:11 Last updated: December 15 2009 22:11


The UK is poorer than it thought it was. This is the most important fact about the crisis. The struggle over the distribution of the losses is going to be brutal. It will be made more so by the second most important fact about the crisis: it has had a huge effect on the public finances. The deficits are unmatched in peacetime.
Happily, the general election would appear to offer a golden opportunity for a debate. Is that not the discussion the country ought to have? Yes. Is it the discussion it is going to have? No. What the government would do if re-elected remains, even after the pre-Budget report, “a riddle, wrapped in a mystery, inside an enigma”, as Churchill said of Stalin’s Russia.
On the Treasury’s current forecasts, the economy will regain 2008 levels of economic activity in 2012. Four years of expected growth would have vanished. In last week’s pre-Budget
report, the Treasury forecast growth of 1.25 per cent next year, 3.5 per cent in 2011 and 2012, then 3.25 per cent in 2013 and 2014. Suppose that growth were to continue at 3.25 per cent a year thereafter. It would still take until 2031 before the economy was as big as it would have been if the 1998-2007 trend had continued. The cumulative loss of output would be 160 per cent of 2007 gross domestic product. If growth after 2014 were at the pre-2008 trend rate, lost GDP would be almost three times 2007 GDP by 2030 (see chart). It is easy to imagine worse possibilities.
These losses in output have had a severe impact on the public finances. Indeed, the fiscal deterioration in the UK has been far bigger than in any other member of the Group of Seven leading high-income countries.
The proximate explanation has been the collapse in government revenues. Between the 2008 Budget and the 2009 pre-Budget report, the forecast of total spending for this financial year has risen by just 4.4 per cent. The forecast of nominal GDP has indeed fallen by 9.1 per cent. But the forecast of revenue has collapsed by 18.1 per cent.
Yet the UK’s recession has not been more severe than that of other high-income countries. As Alistair Darling, the chancellor of the exchequer, noted in his
speech on the pre-Budget report, the cumulative contraction in this recession, up to the third quarter of 2009, has been 3.2 per cent in the US, 5.6 per cent in Germany, 5.9 per cent in Italy, 7.7 per cent in Japan and only 4.75 per cent in the UK. The reason this not particularly dramatic decline in output, by the standards of this “Great Recession”, has had an exceptionally big impact on revenues is that, in the UK, the financial sector played a huge role in supporting consumer expenditure, property transactions and corporate profits. No less than a quarter of corporate taxation came from the financial sector alone. Receipts from corporate taxes fell by 26 per cent between the 12 months to October 2008 and the 12 months to October 2009. Receipts from value added tax fell by 17 per cent over the same period. Over and above the general effect of the recession, this is, to a significant extent, a result of the vulnerability of the UK economy to the disruption in credit and collapse in profits of financial businesses.
What does this imply for the UK’s future? A good way of thinking about this question is that the UK has not only had a financial crisis, with the usual severe impact on output and the public finances, but that the UK has also been a “monocrop” economy, with finance itself acting as the “crop”.
Countries that depend heavily on output and exports of commodities whose markets are volatile are all too familiar with the cycles these can create. In booms, export revenues and government revenues are buoyant, the real exchange rate appreciates and marginal producers of tradeable goods and services are squeezed out – a fate sometimes known as the “Dutch disease” after the impact of discoveries of natural gas on the economy of the Netherlands. Often, both government and the private sector borrow heavily in these good times. Then comes the crash: exports and government revenues collapse, fiscal deficits explode, the exchange rate falls and, quite often, inflation surges and the government defaults.
The biggest mistake one can make in macroeconomics is to confuse the cycle with the trend. In monocrop economies, the danger is particularly big, because cycles can be so large. This, in retrospect, is the mistake the UK made. Thus, the Treasury has decided that the UK’s potential output suddenly fell by 5 per cent during this crisis. This is nonsense, as Robert Chote, director of the Institute for Fiscal Studies, has
suggested. What the Treasury used to consider sustainable output was, instead, the product of the bubble in the UK’s monocrop financial sector, spread, directly and indirectly, to the economy and the public finances.
If this view is right, it has three painful implications: first, properly measured fiscal policy was far looser than was thought during much of Gordon Brown’s period as chancellor; second, it is likely that the UK will suffer not only from a permanent loss of output, but also a permanent decline in the trend rate of economic growth; and, third, a huge fiscal tightening cannot be avoided.
At present, the government envisages a structural fiscal tightening of 5.4 per cent of GDP over two parliamentary terms, much of it unspecified (see chart). It now expects that a third of this will be achieved through higher taxes and two-thirds through cuts in spending. To make this credible, it envisages a fiscal consolidation plan that would, in some incomprehensible manner, be legally binding. Would a defaulting chancellor be taken to the Tower of London? But the problem with the plans is not only that they are barely credible, but also that the envisaged tightening is probably too little and the final level of public sector net debt, at around 60 per cent of GDP, too high for comfort, given the likelihood of further adverse shocks. Even so, cuts in spending are larger than in similar episodes in the postwar period.
While the chancellor has presented overall numbers, he has shied away from exploring the full implications and, still more, the nature of the choices the country faces. This is the debate the UK must have. It must start from a realisation: the country is poorer than was thought. So how should these losses be shared in ways that minimise both the harm done to vulnerable people now and to the country’s economic prospects for the longer term? Those are the big questions in UK politics. Serious politicians must not duck them.